Close Menu
    What's Hot

    Latham & Watkins set to poach star dealmaker from Wachtell Lipton

    June 20, 2025

    Asian-Born Student Picked Barcelona Over America for His MBA

    June 20, 2025

    Labubu: the tiny elf doll driving China’s most valuable toy company

    June 20, 2025
    Facebook X (Twitter) Instagram
    Hot Paths
    • Home
    • News
    • Politics
    • Money
    • Personal Finance
    • Business
    • Economy
    • Investing
    • Markets
      • Stocks
      • Futures & Commodities
      • Crypto
      • Forex
    • Technology
    Facebook X (Twitter) Instagram
    Hot Paths
    Home»Economy»The Inescapable Principle of Comparative Advantage
    Economy

    The Inescapable Principle of Comparative Advantage

    Press RoomBy Press RoomMay 5, 2025No Comments7 Mins Read
    Facebook Twitter Pinterest LinkedIn Tumblr Email
    Share
    Facebook Twitter LinkedIn Pinterest Email


    David Ricardo.
    In a recent article in The Financial Times Nat Dyer argues that economists misunderstand tariffs. He points out that tariffs have political and moral dimensions not captured by standard economic reasoning. We therefore take economists’ widespread advocacy of free trade at our peril: “too few economic theorists have interrogated the actual, messy history of trade.” He concludes that we need “a new, genuinely progressive economics with its eyes focused on the real world and its history, rather than abstract models built on unreality.”

    Economists have long been accused of paying too little attention to reality and too much to models. The accusation is sometimes just. But critics are often guilty of an equally harmful sin: neglecting the truths of economic thought.

    The centerpiece of Dyer’s discussion is David Ricardo. In Chapter 7 of his Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Ricardo exposited the principle of comparative advantage with a discussion of England and Portugal. If England trades cloth with Portugal for wine instead of producing wine itself, it receives wine at a lower cost than if it produced it domestically. If Portugal trades wine with England for cloth, it receives cloth at a lower cost than if it produced it domestically. With exchange and specialization, the amounts of wine and cloth available in both countries will increase.

    Ricardo’s analysis, according to Dyer, is fundamentally flawed because it neglects the historical complexities of English-Portuguese trade relations and the political economy of imperialism more broadly. He quotes Matthew Watson of Warwick University to make the point: Ricardo’s theory is “a mathematical façade behind which the actual historical relations of production of the real England and Portugal are deliberately taken out of the equation.” The relations are “explicitly oppressive social relations of production based on slave labor and the imperial policing of national hierarchies.” For Dyer and Watson, Ricardo’s ignorance—or neglect—of political complexities and moral atrocities discredits not only his analysis but that of the many economists, from Paul Samuelson to Gregory Mankiw, who have followed him down his misguided, historically-illiterate path.

    I know little about English-Portuguese trade relations in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. The complexities of those relations may have been overlooked by Ricardo in his political commentary. I don’t know. But I do know that the complexities have no impact on the analytical content of the principle of comparative advantage. And this principle needs to be reckoned with, irrespective of one’s political persuasions.

    “The principle of comparative advantage as it has come to be taught in standard economics courses is less grandiose than its critics think.”

    The principle of comparative advantage as it has come to be taught in standard economics courses is less grandiose than its critics think. It is not a full-fledged description of how international trade works in practice. It is not a theory of international relations. It is not a comprehensive political program. It is not even a policy position. It is, in fact, an explanation of why two people–or two countries–might choose to trade, even though it looks like they have no reason to do so. And it uses only simple arithmetic!

    Suppose David needs to fix his car. He could do the job himself in three hours. He earns $50 per hour at his accounting job, so fixing the car will cost him $150 in forgone income. Suppose his neighbor’s college-aged son, Adam, offers to fix the car for David. Adam says it will take him five hours. Adam earns $20 per hour working at a local coffeeshop, so David would have to pay him at least $100 for the job. Adam has a comparative advantage in fixing David’s car, even though he is a slower mechanic, because he gives up less in dollar terms ($100) than David ($150) to complete the same job. If David chooses to hire Adam, he can fix his car at a lower cost than if he did the job himself. If Adam chooses to take the job, he can earn more than he would working at the coffeeshop. If David devotes his time to his accounting job and hires Adam to fix his car, both enjoy higher incomes.

    The principle of comparative advantage doesn’t tell us everything we might like to know about David and Adam’s situation. It doesn’t tell us how David acquired his car. It doesn’t tell us whether David likes fixing his car himself, just the fun of it. It doesn’t tell us if Adam’s father mistreats him, or what the working conditions are like in the garage—or the coffeeshop. It doesn’t tell us anything about David’s son, who might like to learn to work on cars but doesn’t seem to have the knack for it. It doesn’t tell us about the personal dynamics and history between David’s family and Adam’s family.

    Some of these details would obviously be relevant for the ethics of it all. But the details are simply not relevant for the principle of comparative advantage. That principle informs us, as a matter of arithmetic, that David can increase his income if he hires Adam to fix his car instead of fixing it himself, even though Adam is a less skilled mechanic, and that Adam also gains from the situation.

    What Dyer is really rejecting when he claims to be rejecting the principle of comparative advantage is the inference from the principle to the conclusion that free trade serves the common social good. Ricardo expressed that inference this way:

    • Under a system of perfectly free commerce, each country naturally devotes its capital and labour to such employments as are most beneficial to each. This pursuit of individual advantage is admirably connected with the universal good of the whole.

    The rejection of Ricardo’s logic in the statement flows from moral convictions about historical injustices, perceptions of continuing power imbalances, and more. Dyer writes: “All major economic powers—Britain, Germany, and yes the USA, and China-rose to their position while protecting their industries with high tariffs.”

    Moral convictions, power dynamics, and so on should impact how we think about trade policy in practice. Certain convictions and claims might incline us towards or against trade liberalization and the historical Ricardian policy position. But they in fact take nothing away from the analytical principle of comparative advantage.

    Jubilantly declaring the second death of Ricardo, as Peter Navarro did in 2019, has no bearing on the enduring truths Ricardo uncovered in parts of his analysis. Claiming that trade is complex in practice cannot change the fact that every choice has a cost; the cost is always an opportunity forgone; we each increase our productive output and the output of others by specializing in the activities that cost us the least and exchanging. This is logic and arithmetic.

    For more on these topics, see

    One might conclude that there are good reasons for protectionism (I don’t). But arguments for protectionism or a “genuinely progressive economics,” to be serious, have to take the principle of comparative advantage seriously, just as they have to take arithmetic seriously. That means admitting that there will absolutely be clear costs—material benefits forgone—by restricting trade. Historical and political complexities change that fact no more than they change the fact that water runs downhill.



    Source link

    Share. Facebook Twitter Pinterest LinkedIn Tumblr Email
    Press Room

    Related Posts

    Getting “Screwed” on Trade? – Econlib

    June 19, 2025

    Joshua Rothman on the future of reading

    June 19, 2025

    June is Liberty Month – Econlib

    June 19, 2025
    Leave A Reply Cancel Reply

    LATEST NEWS

    Latham & Watkins set to poach star dealmaker from Wachtell Lipton

    June 20, 2025

    Asian-Born Student Picked Barcelona Over America for His MBA

    June 20, 2025

    Labubu: the tiny elf doll driving China’s most valuable toy company

    June 20, 2025

    Trump Says Number of Holidays Must Change in Juneteenth Post

    June 20, 2025
    POPULAR
    Business

    The Business of Formula One

    May 27, 2023
    Business

    Weddings and divorce: the scourge of investment returns

    May 27, 2023
    Business

    How F1 found a secret fuel to accelerate media rights growth

    May 27, 2023
    Advertisement
    Load WordPress Sites in as fast as 37ms!

    Archives

    • June 2025
    • May 2025
    • April 2025
    • March 2025
    • February 2025
    • January 2025
    • December 2024
    • November 2024
    • April 2024
    • March 2024
    • February 2024
    • January 2024
    • December 2023
    • November 2023
    • October 2023
    • September 2023
    • May 2023

    Categories

    • Business
    • Crypto
    • Economy
    • Forex
    • Futures & Commodities
    • Investing
    • Market Data
    • Money
    • News
    • Personal Finance
    • Politics
    • Stocks
    • Technology

    Your source for the serious news. This demo is crafted specifically to exhibit the use of the theme as a news site. Visit our main page for more demos.

    We're social. Connect with us:

    Facebook X (Twitter) Instagram Pinterest YouTube

    Subscribe to Updates

    Get the latest creative news from FooBar about art, design and business.

    Facebook X (Twitter) Instagram Pinterest
    • Home
    • Buy Now
    © 2025 ThemeSphere. Designed by ThemeSphere.

    Type above and press Enter to search. Press Esc to cancel.